Social Progress Derailed: The New Gravy Express Train-Programmed Response?

Pinterest
Copy
WhatsApp
Open Modal

Share this on

Print
Open Modal

Print content

Reading Time: 11 minutes
Help keep family & friends informed by sharing this article

To:

The Right Honourable Justin Trudeau, PC, MP, Prime Minister of Canada 

The Honourable Bill Morneau, PC, Minister of Finance 

Mr. Nathaniel Erskine-Smith, MP, House of Commons 

Dear Prime Minister, Minister, and Mr. Erskine-Smith,

Last year an e-petition was submitted to the government requesting that the Bank of Canada fulfill its stated role “to promote the economic and financial welfare of Canada,” by returning to previous levels of monetary financing and economic activity1, as opposed to only focusing on inflation through the blunt and indirect instrument of influencing short-term interest rates in overnight markets. 

Minister Morneau’s response to the petition was troubling, as it cites disproven assumptions about inflation that Canada’s own history belies. Empirical evidence shows that higher levels of federal monetary financing did not effect inflation in Canada2, the most recent proof being that when, in 20113, Harper increased the monetary financing of the BoC 33% for three years, inflation actually decreased4. Careful analyses of instances of hyperinflation, by institutions like the IMF, have proven that public money creation alone is never the culprit; speculation, corruption, a poor understanding of monetary policy and economics, and market forces are of greater influence5

Claiming that government monetary financing is inflationary, ignores that private, bank money creation dwarfs government money creation at approximately 97%6 of our money supply created as debt with interest attached7. It is their loans and credit that have caused consumer debt to rise to nearly 170% of average income and over 100% of GDP8, while also inflating asset prices resulting in the soaring housing prices in Toronto and Vancouver9. The elimination of reserve requirements at the BoC in 1991, replaced by the amorphous and ephemeral capital requirements, ensured that what little direct control over the money supply the BoC had was gone10. Also disproving the notion is that the massive amounts of QE injected into various economies after the ’08 crisis did not inflate to consumer prices either (although it did inflate asset prices)11

However the most alarmingly ironic statements come from our current BoC governor Mr. Poloz12. In selling the notion that a nation with a public central bank counter-intuitively needs foreign investment to fund public infrastructure, he then lists two projects, the St. Lawrence Seaway and the Trans-Canada Highway, which required no foreign investment whatsoever and were primarily funded through monetary financing using the Bank of Canada. The St. Lawrence Seaway did not need US investment, in fact, after the US dragged its heels for too long Canada threatened to go it alone13, and the US finally got involved because it would not have a claim to any revenues if they didn’t share the cost. Either Mr. Poloz is intentionally misleading the public on this history, or he is unaware of the history of the institution he is leading. 

The two most economically beneficial banks in the history of Canada are the Bank of Canada and the Industrial Development Bank (now the BDC). Both had the same auspicious beginnings with a capitalization injection of publicly created funds14. At the same time the BoC was nationalized in 1938, the government enacted Bill 143, the Municipal Improvements Assistance Act, which allowed municipalities to borrow directly from the federal government for building municipal infrastructure15. The Bank of Canada was once the largest holder of federal debt, using monetary financing to bring us into the unprecedented growth of our golden years in the post-war period, funding many important public infrastructure projects like the St. Lawrence Seaway, Trans Canada Highway, and early parts of the 401 Highway. More importantly, we had no problem using the BoC to fund our efforts in WWII16. Why can’t we use it for peaceful purposes as we did until we joined the Bank for International Settlements’ first Basel Committee in 197417 and proceeded to adopt monetarism, the now disproven notion that the money supply is the main driver of inflation18. The resulting increase in federal debt after 1974 is painfully clear19, and was a direct and immediate result of these policy changes. The following year the government rescinded Bill 143 in line with the dictates of the BIS. Monetarism forced increased private sector borrowing instead of public money creation, and since then the federal share of the total public debt burden has been downloaded onto the provincial and municipal levels20 and is set to further burden cities now that the 2017 budget has reduced their access to federal funding21

Let’s say the government needs to build $1 billion in new infrastructure. It can either create the money with the Bank of Canada or borrow the funds selling bonds in capital markets 

Either way, $1 billion is spent on public goods, it will have the same result economically and socially and create exactly the same number of jobs and result in the same physical asset22. The only difference is that if the money is borrowed, it has to be paid back with interest. 

It is most worrying to hear Prime Min ister Trudeau speak to business audiences wooing them with promises of high returns with an unnecessary Canada Infrastructure Bank23, when, in the Bank of Canada, we already have one that does not require private investors. The greatest concern of all however, comes from the government’s admission, allowance, and dismissal of the obvious conflict of interest in the government allowing a council heavily tilted in favour of big business interests (representatives from BlackRock, the world’s largest asset manager, and McKinsey & Co.) to devise the plans for the infrastructure bank that will facilitate the high returns on their investments24. Despite the clear conflict, no disclosures were made and no one recused himself for any of the council decisions. The government worked for months with these advisors to prepare for the closed door meeting, organized by BlackRock, between Prime Minister Trudeau and institutional investors. BlackRock even tailored and vetted the Infrastructure Minister’s presentation to ensure it was what investors wanted to hear. Furthering the conflict of interest is Michael Sabia, the president of the Caisse who wants $1.3 billion from Ottawa for light rail, leading policy discussions on the CIB as a member of Minister Morneau’s Advisory Council on Economic Growth. How are Canadians to have faith in a bank structured by the very players that will profit from it? 

The manner in which the infrastructure bank was presented in legislation does little to inspire faith in it either. Following in Harper’s tradition the CIB was jammed into the undemocratic omnibus Bill C-44 stifling debate25. The Senate is considering the need to debate the CIB legislation separately26, as such an important change to our system should be. Even a KPMG report for Infrastructure Canada itself cautions against rushing in, before more impacts can be considered27

With our debt as high as it is (over $1 trillion and counting28) and inequality worsening29, why would we make it worse, promising above average returns and monetizing public infrastructure into a revenue stream for private investors? Even without public money creation, we can use traditional bond issues at a lower rate than investors would expect from an infrastructure bank30. The proposed infrastructure bank is a huge deviation from the Liberal election platform to “use its strong credit rating and lending authority to make it easier and more affordable for municipalities to build the projects their communities need.”31 Multiple studies from around the world have proven that using private investment to build assets, for example P3s, costs the public more money, as evidenced by Ontario’s Auditor General32 and the reversal of privatizations in Europe33

Are you suggesting an infrastructure bank to build infrastructure or to provide a new revenue stream for large institutional investors? How exactly are we supposed to pay back investors? Are you planning to saddle the new infrastructure with user fees so that they become an ongoing revenue stream? Why do documents show that the government plans to take on more risk to ensure that investors get paid first, and the government last34? For how much more debt will taxpayers be on the hook? We already made our debt worse when, in February this year, the BoC reduced its automatic minimum purchase of government bonds from 15% to 14%, increasing our debt burden for no apparent reason except perhaps to increase the available general collateral in overnight markets35. Harper’s first budget in a majority government cranked the rate up to 20% to suit his needs; the BoC market notice makes clear that it was done “to accommodate the planned increase in government deposits held at the Bank of Canada associated with the Government of Canada’s plan announced in the June 2011 budget to increase its prudential liquidity over the next 3 fiscal years”3. Not the BoC’s plan, the Government of Canada’s plan, so why can’t we do the same? The BoC is not autonomous; the disagreement with Governor Coyne that necessitated an additional clause in the BoC Act proves that36, as does the disagreements with Governor Crow that led to his not being renewed for another term37

We don’t need to be a source of unearned income for investment funds, and we don’t need to sell off public assets. These are capital assets. “The cost of acquiring fixed assets is treated as expenditure at the time of acquisition” 38 instead of being depreciated over the life of the asset as private assets are. That capital cost is also accounted for in the same budget as the operating budget providing services, unlike municipalities’ ability to separate capital and operating expenditures39. The net effect is to make deficits appear worse than they are. If we really need money we’re not willing to create ourselves, we should be going after the billions in tax avoidance and evasion and closing the loopholes that allow it40, or raising corporate tax rates. Canada itself has become a tax haven as evidenced by Burger King’s acquisition of Tim Horton’s41, and Canada has now hit an unenviable milestone, for the first time ever getting more tax revenue from people than from businesses42

We need to provide the public with the infrastructure and services needed to ensure a high standard of living befitting a country of our wealth. Deficits are mere accounting, and recent economic studies have proven that austerity shrinks economies and deficit spending grows them43

I hope you let evidence and history, and not the specious assumptions espoused by neoliberal institutions like BlackRock, McKinsey & Co, the Chicago School, the London School of Economics, and the private banking community, guide you to the conclusion that we already have the ultimate driver of prosperity and growth: The Bank of Canada. 

Thank you for your time, 

Adam Smith, Toronto, Ontario 

Our Comment 

Adam Smith is a young community activist who works in visual effects for feature film and television. 

He is working with COMER’s elected Executive, to further study banking and monetary reform, and to contribute his considerable skills and abilities to the work of COMER. 

He seeks to promote a political economy that will provide equality of opportunity for all, and function in the best interest of the common good. 

It’s especially encouraging to find young Canadians taking such quality initiatives. 

It’s hard to believe that any politician could be so unresponsive as to dismiss a submission of such quality, with a stock reply that simply ignores or denies the evidence. Adam also emailed every senator. 

Élan 

End Notes 

  1. https://petitions.parl.gc.ca/en/Petition/Details? Petition=e-337
  1. Figure 1: Monetary financing and inflation in Canada, 1958–2012 “Is Monetary Financing Inflationary? A Case Study of the Canadian Economy, 1935-1975” by Josh Ryan- Collins www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp_848.pdf. www.thestar. com/opinion/commentary/2015/01/17/monetarism-is-deadfinally. html
  1. www.bankofcanada.ca/2011/10/change-minimum-nominalbond- purchases
  1. https://thecanadianpress-a.akamaihd.net/graphics/2016/ static/cp-cda-inflation-feb.png
  1. Quote about hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic from the IMF: “This episode can therefore clearly not be blamed on excessive money printing by a government-run central bank, but rather on a combination of excessive reparations claims and of massive money creation by private speculators, aided and abetted by a private central bank” (https://positivemoney. org/2015/12/hyperinflation-how-the-wrong-lessons-werelearned- from-weimar-and-zimbabwe-a-history-of-pqe-part- 2-of-8). 
  1. M0 divided by M3. www.tradingeconomics.com/canada/ money-supply-m3
  1. www.lop.parl.gc.ca/Content/LOP/ResearchPublications/ 2015-51-e.html?cat=economics. 8.
  2. https://business.financialpost.com/news/economy/canadashousehold- debt-is-now-bigger-than-its-gdp-for-the-first-time
  1. https://business.financialpost.com/news/economy/bankof- canada-warns-elevated-housing-market-a-major-risk-withhigh- prices-in-vancouver-toronto-unsustainable
  1. https://gilliganscorner.wordpress.com/2008/04/06/ canadas-private-banks-have-no-reserve-requirements. 
  1. https://tsi-blog.com/2015/11/why-hasnt-the-feds-qecaused- inflation. www.theregister.co.uk/2015/06/07/so_why_ didnt_quantitative_easing_produce_huge_inflation. https:// themarketmogul.com/brief-history-quantitative-easing
  1. www.macleans.ca/economy/for-the-record-stephen-polozon- canadian-economic-openness
  1. “However, the project was met with resistance from railway and port lobbyists in the US, and hampered by war and depression in the first half of the century. After rejecting numerous agreements to construct a Seaway, the US Senate finally assented in 1954 when Canada declared it was ready to proceed unilaterally with its own Seaway.” https://web.archive.org/ web/20080625044719/www.infrastructure.gc.ca/researchrecherche/ result/alt_formats/pdf/hm05_e.pdf
  1. “The Prime Minister, as a reflationary measure, introduced legislation calling for an expenditure of $39 million on public works to be financed by an expansion of the note issue” (The Bank of Canada: Origins and Early History by George S. Watts). “The Bank of Canada subscribed for the full initial stock issue of $25 million and as funds were required drew it down and paid for it. By starting off with only equity money and no borrowed funds, the new Bank (IDB) was to have a favourable start and develop some strength and attractiveness in its operating record before it should have to borrow and pay interest” (The IDB: A History of Canada’s Industrial Development Bank by E. Ritchie Clark; for context, that is $652 million and $418 million respectively in today’s dollars). 
  1. “This Bill authorizes the Minister of Finance, with the approval of the Governor in Council, to enter into agreements to make loans to municipalities to enable them to pay the whole or part of the cost of constructing or making extension, or improvements to or renewals of a municipal waterworks system, gas plant, electric light system or any other self-liquidating project.” www.dropbox.com/s/hftdt0yn5uvzkgo/C-143. pdf?dl=0. 1
  1. “During the war period, $517.8 million of securities were bought directly from the government with newly created central bank money and by converting numerous maturing securities into new Government of Canada issues (Neufeld 1958a, 145; Mcivor 1958, 174). As Plumptre (1941, 155–56) remarks, the effect of this increase in note issue was to provide “a sort of interest-free loan to the Government through the medium of the Bank of Canada.” The Bank issued the notes at virtually zero cost to itself, whilst the profits paid to it by the government for holding government debt were all paid back to government which owned all of its stock.” www.levyinstitute. org/pubs/wp_848.pdf. 
  1. www.bis.org/bcbs/history.html
  1. www.thestar.com/opinion/commentary/2015/01/17/ monetarism-is-dead-finally.html
  1. www.fraserinstitute.org/sites/default/files/authors/ brief%20history%2012.png. 
  1. Chart 4: Asset Shares By Order of Government, General Government, 1955–2011. www.policyalternatives.ca/sites/ default/files/uploads/publications/National%20 Office/2013/01/Canada’s%20Infrastructure%20Gap_0.pdf
  1. www.theglobeandmail.com//report-on-business/economy/ ottawa-eyes-more-private-cash-in-infrastructure-push/article34392164. 
  1. “If a loan funds the building of a house, or a railway or a broadband network, it is creating a productive asset. A productive asset creates value over many years, providing a continuous flow of increased products and services over time. Money spent on such an asset should thus be able to be absorbed in to the economy without creating inflation” (https://b.3cdn.net/ nefoundation/e79789e1e31f261e95_ypm6b49z7.pdf). 
  1. www.cbc.ca/news/politics/trudeau-public-privateinfrastructure- 1.3850155
  1. www.theglobeandmail.com/news/politics/liberals-gaveinvestors- extraordinary-control-over-infrastructure-bank-opposition/ article34910106. www.theglobeandmail.com/news/ politics/ottawas-dealings-to-secure-infrastructure-funds-raisequestions/ article34904963
  1. www.theglobeandmail.com/news/politics/ndp-forcescommons- debate-on-infrastructure-bank/article34945759.
  1. www.theglobeandmail.com/news/politics/senators-discussremoval- of-infrastructure-bank-from-omnibus-budget-bill/ article35011859
  1. www.theglobeandmail.com/news/politics/be-extremelycareful- in-launching-infrastructure-bank-internal-reportwarns- ottawa/article34952796. 
  1. www.nationaldebtclocks.org/debtclock/Canada
  1. www.conferenceboard.ca/hcp/details/society/incomeinequality.aspx
  1. “There’s no shortage of low-cost public financing available to Canadian governments. Ottawa can now borrow at 0.6 percent over a year and issue 30-year bonds at 1.8 percent, with provinces a percentage point higher. Long-term borrowing rates have never been this low. Meanwhile large private infrastructure investors expect ‘stable, predictable returns in the 7 to 9 percent range’…It doesn’t take an economist to understand it makes no sense to finance projects at seven to nine percent when you can do so at two percent” (https://canadians. org/blog/trudeau-government-announces-privatizationbank). “This argument doesn’t hold up. Borrowing money is largely a balance sheet transaction, and if it’s used to invest in infrastructure there will be assets to match these liabilities for many years to come,” the report states. Further, they note that Canada has the lowest net debt-to-GDP ratio of the Group of Seven countries by far. “The case for establishing the CIB is not compelling, as it has the potential to increase overall costs to taxpayers while privatizing the most high-return, low-risk infrastructure assets….” (www.theglobeandmail.com/news/ politics/case-for-canada-infrastructure-bank-not-compellingresearchers- warn/article34898110). 
  1. www.liberal.ca/wp-content/uploads/2015/10/New-planfor- a-strong-middle-class.pdf
  1. www.theglobeandmail.com/news/politics/private-partnerships-cost-ontario-taxpayers-8-billion-auditor-general/article22012009
  1. “A growing number of cities worldwide deciding to end their experiments with privatisation. Since 2007, 170 municipalities in Germany alone have brought energy services back into public hands. Globally, at least 100 cities have done the same with privatised water services over the past 15 years, including dozens of municipalities in France – once seen as a growing focus for water privatisation” (www.theguardian.com/ cities/2014/nov/12/hamburg-global-reverse-privatisation-cityservices). 
  1. https://ipolitics.ca/2017/05/31/documents-raise-newquestions- about-taxpayer-risk-in-liberal-infrastructure-bank
  1. www.bankofcanada.ca/2017/02/bank-canada-announcesreduction- minimum-amount-government
  1. “Minister’s directive (2) If, notwithstanding the consultations provided for in subsection (1), there should emerge a difference of opinion between the Minister and the Bank concerning the monetary policy to be followed, the Minister may, after consultation with the Governor and with the approval of the Governor in Council, give to the Governor a written directive concerning monetary policy, in specific terms and applicable for a specified period, and the Bank shall comply with that directive” (https://laws-lois.justice.gc.ca/eng/acts/B-2/ FullText.html). 
  1. “This will mean discarding the polite fiction that the Bank has any real say over, and therefore responsibility for, monetary policy formulation – however convenient that story may be for the government and however flattering the Bank of Canada may find it” (Making Money by John Crow). 
  1. www.statcan.gc.ca/pub/68f0023x/2006001/chap/chap7- eng.htm
  1. “An Ontario municipality may issue long-term debt only for capital purposes and cannot borrow for operations…. Repayment of municipal debt is amortized over the term of the debenture with regular contributions being made to the sinking fund” (www1.toronto.ca/wps/portal/contentonly?vgnextoid= ace3c1b8c8412410VgnVCM10000071d60f89RCRD). 
  1. www.thestar.com/news/world/2016/06/17/offshore-taxavoidance- fixing-it-made-it-worse.html
  1. https://www.cbc.ca/news/business/burger-king-tim-hortonsdeal- skirts-taxes-u-s-group-says-1.2871070
  1. www.huffingtonpost.ca/2013/11/24/corporate-personaltaxes- canada_n_4333694.html
  1. “Since the global turn to austerity in 2010, every country that introduced significant austerity has seen its economy suffer, with the depth of the suffering closely related to the harshness of the austerity… Meanwhile, all of the economic research that allegedly supported the austerity push has been discredited… An economy that is depressed even with zero interest rates is, in effect, an economy in which the public is trying to save more than businesses are willing to invest. In such an economy the government does everyone a service by running deficits and giving frustrated savers a chance to put their money to work. Nor does this borrowing compete with private investment. An economy where interest rates cannot go any lower is an economy awash in desired saving with no place to go, and deficit spending that expands the economy is, if anything, likely to lead to higher private investment than would otherwise materialise” (“The Austerity Delusion” by Paul Krugman in www.theguardian.com/business/ng-interactive/2015/apr/29/ the-austerity-delusion). https://michael-hudson.com/2017/03/ why-deficits-hurt-banking-profits.

Share Now

Add a Comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Stay Informed,
Join Our Mailing List.
Its Free.

Your Information is safe: Privacy Policy

Support Comer

Your donations will help fund our research, education, and outreach activities as well as help cover our expenses.

Related Articles:

Stay Informed, Join Our Mailing List. Its Free.

Your Information is safe: Privacy Policy

Join our Mailing List to stay informed